Skip to main content
Login | Suomeksi | På svenska | In English

Browsing by discipline "Economics"

Sort by: Order: Results:

  • Lagerspetz, Mattias (2016)
    This thesis examines the drivers behind the formation of housing prices in Tallinn, Estonia. The focus is, more specifically, on the relation between changes in demographics and housing prices. There will be significant changes in Tallinn’s demographic composition in the years to come, as the number of births in Tallinn have declined steeply from the 1990s on. Past studies have shown, that most significant increase in people’s demand for housing occurs in their 20s, and as such the sharp fall in the number of young people in Tallinn, could result in a decrease of demand for housing. First, a model suitable for examining demographics’ effect on housing is introduced. In the model demand for housing by age-group is first estimated from cross-sectional data. Next, the obtained estimates are combined with demographic time series data to obtain a demographic demand time series. Lastly, the relations between housing prices and demographic demand (as well as other macroeconomic variables) are examined. Results from a number of previous studies employing a similar model are also presented. In the empirical section of this thesis, a similar model is applied on data from Tallinn, spanning from 1997 to 2014. Firstly, the demand for housing by age-group is estimated from cross-sectional data obtained by combining estimates for the value of almost 170 000 Tallinn housing units with the inhabitants of the units, as reported in Estonian 2011 census data. Next, the demand estimates are combined with time-series of past demographic data on Tallinn, to construct a total demographic demand time series variable. Thirdly, the long-run relationships between housing prices, demographic demand and other macroeconomic variables are examined using cointegration analysis. Tallinn housing prices are modelled in vector error correction model framework, along with the obtained demographic demand, GDP per capita, as well as other macroeconomic time series. Housing prices’ long run elasticity estimates obtained are generally in line with results from previous studies. However, the results seem quite sensitive regarding model specification. Importantly, effects of increases in demographic demand on housing prices are found to be negative for some of the alternative model specifications. The forecasted changes in future demographic demand are also of not a very great magnitude, so the predictions for future housing prices for the models are affected relatively modestly by the forecasted changes in demographic demand.
  • Kinnunen, Aleksi (2015)
    In this thesis, I study the determinants of Finland-Sweden bond yield spread during 1995-2013 by using the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) approach. I form different regression models, where Finland-Sweden 10-year bond yield spread is dependent variable and variables, based on the bond pricing theory, are explanatory variables. In addition to the regression analysis, I conduct a plot analysis, in which I aim to study whether there are any certain events that may have affected the bond yield spread. The idea behind the plot analysis is that the EMU membership of Finland may have increased the bond yield spread, mainly due to the lack of a lender of last resort. The results from the regression analysis suggest that risk aversion was possibly an important determinant of Finland-Sweden bond yield spread developments during the crisis period 07/2007-12/2013. The risk aversion was measured by the VIX-index. The study also finds some support that other things rather than country specific fiscal fundamentals where driving the bond yield spread during 01/1995-12/2013. The plot analysis results suggest that It is possible that the convergence of bond yields across euro countries and Sweden, were one reason for bond yield spread developments before the crisis period. The results also show that the announcement of the new European Central Bank`s Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) program in 2012, likely started the fall in the bond yield spread. In addition, during the crisis period, Finland`s bond yield may have benefited from the global risk aversion but not as much as Germany and Sweden.
  • Markkanen, Valtteri (2017)
    Abstract Student selection has been a widely researched topic in economics and a lot of the literature has focused on how the student’s performance in the university can be predicted. In Finland most of the people applying to a university take an entrance exam and the admittance is determined by both the entrance exam and the score from high school’s end exam – the matriculation examination. Basing the student selection on the entrance exam has aroused a lot of criticism claiming that it can be unpredictable for the applicant and that it slows down the transition from secondary to tertiary education. Currently the Finnish Government is urging universities to abandon overly burdensome entrance exams in favor of basing the student selection more on the matriculation exam scores. In this thesis I examine how well success in matriculation exam and university’s entrance exam predict later performance in the university. The data used comes from the student registry of University of Helsinki where I will focus on students who applied to the Faculties of Law and Social Sciences in years 2011 and 2012. The student’s performance in the university is measured by his or her grade point average and the study pace. The results show that the matriculation exam and entrance exam are both statistically significant and positive predictors for university grade point average but matriculation exam score has much more substantial effect. For students in the Faculty of Law matriculation exam score explains 17 % of the variance in the grade point average while the entrance exam accounts for 2 %. Results for the Faculty of Social Sciences support the findings with matriculation exam explaining 13 % and entrance exam just 1 %. Both variables fail to predict the study pace. The findings from these two faculties support the notion that matriculation exam score is a better predictor for academic success than entrance exam score in terms of grade point average.
  • Peltola, Juuso (2017)
    In this thesis the existence of Long Tail effect in Finnish music industry is studied. The Long Tail effect is defined as the expansion of music supply to include a higher number of niche products instead of focusing on fewer ‘superstar’ hits. Emergency of ‘superstar’ hits has been the trend in entertainment industry since the invention of mass media and music recording, but new technological innovations can start to challenge it. The source of the Long Tail effect is in newer technological innovations, such as online distribution services and digital production tools, which lower the cost of producing music and distributing it to customers. Previously the costs of production and distribution limited the amount of producers that entered the market, but with new technologies the barrier of entry is lower than ever. This allows higher number of producers to produce music and bring it to the market, thus expanding the variety of supply. The new products won’t take hits’ place on the top of the charts, but they can take bigger share of the market than before. The goal of this thesis is to study whether the Long Tail effect exists in Finnish music market or not. To do this the record companies are assumed to produce commercial and creative output, and production functions for both are defined. Then two hypotheses are formed regarding these outputs and digitalization. First hypothesis states that if the Long Tail effect exists, the creative output is higher for firms that have adapted to digitalization. Second hypothesis is that if the Long Tail effect exist, the commercial output is not affected by the adaption to digitalization. To test the hypotheses, empirical data for 52 record companies is collected and used. Business register data is used to measure companies commercial output, labor input and capital inputs. National Library legal deposit database is used to measure creative output and intangible capital input. A measurement for digitalization is created by observing the availability of companies’ releases in YouTube and Spotify. Commercial output is estimated from the empirical data with OLS regression model and creative output is estimated with Negative Binomial regression model. The significance of digitalization is tested for both outputs. The results for these estimations show that in case of commercial output, none of digitalization variables used in the estimation affects the output. This is in line with the hypothesis regarding commercial output, which supports the existence of Long Tail effect. In case of creative output, all digitalization variables have significant and positive effect on the output. This is in line with the hypothesis regarding creative output, which supports the existence of Long Tail effect. Similar estimations are also done for second dataset, where three largest companies are excluded as potential outliers. The results for this dataset are the same. Digitalization doesn’t affect commercial output, but it increases the creative output. Conclusions from the results of this thesis are that they support the existence of Long Tail effect in Finnish music market. The two hypotheses that support the Long Tail effect were that digitalization doesn’t affect the commercial output and digitalization increases the creative output, and the results show that both hypotheses are true. For robustness the estimation was done for a second dataset where three largest companies were excluded as potential outliers, and results from this estimation also support the existence of Long Tail effect.
  • Tervonen, Lassi (2016)
    Finnish high schools are different in terms Matriculation Examination results. In some of the schools the results are very good on average. However, schools also differ in terms of student characteristics and some of the schools can be seen as ‘elite’, at least in terms of academic ability. If elite high schools students end up with good results in Matriculation Examination, to what extent the results are due to the school environment and to what extent due to the baseline characteristics of students? The Finnish National Joint Application procedure allocates students to general upper secondary schools based on applicants’ preferences and comprehensive school grade point average (GPA). Schools have limited number of seats, which means that they can admit only a limited number of applicants. This procedure leads to an entrance threshold, which determines a cutoff GPA for every school. This study’s focus is on schools in the Helsinki Capital Region which have very high entrance threshold. Those who have GPA above the cutoff are offered a seat, while those who have GPA below the cutoff are not. Because this cutoff is determined randomly, a regression discontinuity design (RDD) can be used to obtain a quasi-experimental setting. RDD exploits thresholds as a rule assigning applicants just above and just below the threshold to treatment and control groups, respectively. This makes it possible to estimate causal elite high school effects using rich data sources containing information on students’ application preferences, GPA, background characteristics, enrollment, Matriculation Examination results, and the cutoff GPAs. However, due to imperfect compliance, the enrollment to elite high schools is probabilistic, so only the elite high school offers are randomized. These offers are used to estimate intention-to-treat effects. Also, by using the offer as an instrumental variable to elite high school enrollment, the effect of enrollment is estimated. This is done by using fuzzy RDD, which allows for imperfect compliance. These estimates represent local average treatment effects for compliers, i.e., for those whose enrollment is determined by their offer status. An elite high school offer gives a possibility to study with high-achieving peers in terms of comprehensive school GPA. The peer group one gets is also often more homogenous in terms of GPA. In some cases, the peers are also more often female and have more often highly educated parents. Nevertheless, intention-to-treat and local average treatment effect estimates suggest that receiving an offer to an elite high school or enrolling to an elite high school does not have systematic positive or negative effect on learning outcomes, as measured by Matriculation Examination results. These results can be seen as evidence against the importance of peer group in terms of learning outcomes. On the other hand, attending in an elite high school can be beneficial in some other way that is not observed in Matriculation Examination grades.
  • Mytty, Tuukka (2013)
    Does carbon dioxide predict temperature? No it does not, in the time period of 1880-2004 with the carbon dioxide and temperature data used in this thesis. According to the Inter Governmental Panel on Climate Change(IPCC) carbon dioxide is the most important factor in raising the global temperature. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that carbon dioxide truly predicts temperature. Because this paper uses observational data it has to be kept in mind that no causality interpretation can be made, only predictive inferences. The data is from the years 1880-2004 and consists of carbon dioxide emissions and temperature anomalies, the base period for the anomalies is 1961-1990. The main analysis method is the cointegrated VAR model but also the standard VAR model is used. The variables were tested for possible unit roots and it was found that there were unit roots present. Then the variables were tested for the cointegrating rank and here the analysis divided into three parts. One, with the assumptions that the variables are integrated of order one, a constant as a deterministic term and one cointegrating relation. Two, variables are allowed to be integrated of order two, a linear trend as a deterministic term and one cointegrating relation. Three, based on some weak evidence there was a result that variables weren’t cointegrated and the analysis could be done in differences. In the first the case it the result was that carbon dioxide doesn’t predict temperature but actually temperature predicted carbon dioxide, the second version gave the same result. In the third case neither one of the variables predicted the other one. These results go against the what is considered as the common consensus in the subject matter of climate change.
  • Kalmbach, Aino (2015)
    Even though female education has boomed in recent decades, women remain underrepresented in study fields such as science, technology, engineering and mathematics (STEM) both in the number of students as in the number of graduates. Female underrepresentation in STEM study fields leads to inefficiency, if top talents opt out of STEM education regardless of their relatively higher ability. In this Master’s thesis I study the effect of culture on female underrepresentation in STEM study fields. Previous literature has linked female underrepresentation in STEM to e.g. differences in preferences, ability and competitiveness. The number of studies on the effect of culture on economic outcomes has been increasing in the 2000s. In this thesis, I use the epidemiological approach that has been used in previous literature on the subject. The approach studies the economic decisions of immigrants, as they differ by their cultural background but face the same markets and institutions in Finland. Thus, differences in cultural background would possibly lead to e.g. different educational decisions. I use a panel dataset from Statistics Finland. I concentrate on the cross-section of the year 2012. The dataset consists of two samples: firstly, a sample of immigrants who have moved to Finland not older than 10 years of age and who are 18-36 years old at the time of observation. Secondly, a 1/3 random sample of the 18—36 year old individuals in the original population is included. In this thesis I find that the culture of an immigrant woman’s country of origin is correlated with the likelihood of her enrolling in a STEM major study subject at the tertiary degree in Finland. I measure the culture of the country of origin by an odds ratio that reflects the likelihood of being a female STEM graduate in the country of origin. The result implies that women, who are originally from cultures where female share in STEM is relatively larger, have a higher likelihood to enrol in STEM in Finland, too. The sample size, however, very small due to the small amount of immigrants in Finland and limitations in the data. Hence, no definitive conclusions can be drawn from the result. The education of the parents of the immigrants is not tabulated in the data, so it is not possible to distinguish whether the higher likelihood to enrol in STEM is due to a higher likelihood to have a parent who is a professional in STEM.
  • Vänskä, Bettina (2014)
    In contrast to conventional economic growth theory, natural resource abundance can harm country's economic growth. This puzzling phenomenon is called resource curse. Resource curse is defined as a decrease in national income due to an increase of natural resources. In general, resource rich countries have had lower growth rates than their resource poor counterparts during last four decades. However, not all resource abundant countries perform poorly. There are also countries with large natural resources that have experienced fast economic growth. Recent studies have suggested that institutional quality could explain this divergence. By institutions it is referred for example to the level of corruption, rule of law and government accountability. This thesis examines whether institutional quality has any effect on resource curse and whether differences in institutional quality explain the divergence between well and poorly performing resource abundant countries. The problem is examined with two rent-seeking theories. The first one (Mehlum et al. 2006a) examines entrepreneurs' allocation between two competing activities: production and rent-seeking activity. The institutional quality of the country determines whether or not natural resources induce the entrepreneurs to participate in rent-seeking activity. The second theory (Robinson and Torvik 2013) differs from Mehlum et al. in the specialization possibility and functional forms used. It shows that the allocation decision of entrepreneurs and the aggregate income of the country are conditional on the institutional quality of the country. Both theories examine how entrepreneurs' allocation decision and national income respond to an increase in natural resources. Resource curse is shown to exist only in countries with poor institutions. In that case an increase in natural resources decreases national income because talents are transferred into rent-seeking activity. Strong institutions mitigate the entrepreneurs’ participation to rent-seeking activity. As more entrepreneurs are participating in production activity and incentives to participate in rent-seeking are mitigated, the national income is increased. Institutional quality determines whether a resource rich country suffers from resource curse. Institutions are shown to be essential in explaining the divergence of resource rich countries to well and poorly performing. Resource rich country can turn the curse over by improving its institutions. The results stress the importance of underlying institutions on economic performance.
  • Mitrunen, Matti (2013)
    Job polarization, loss of middle skilled employment relative to low and high skilled, has been visible in many western countries in the past decades (Goos et al. 2009), but its causes are not completely understood. Most of the research blames uneven technological change, which allows machinery to replace routine middle skilled work (Autor et al. 2003, Autor & Dorn 2012), but cheap foreign workforce could also contribute to the job polarization trend by replacing middle skilled manufacturing labour. This relationship between job polarization and offshoring has been explored with indices, but not with actual trade data. The contribution of this thesis is to show the Finnish job polarization trend in detail, and use firm-level imports data to examine its relation to offshoring. I have in my disposal Structure of Earnings Statistics, Finnish Longitudinal Employer-Employee Data and firm-level imports data from 2000 to 2008. These data allow me to illustrate job polarization trend in Finland, as well as the trend within firms. I divide Finnish labour in low, middle and high skilled occupations, and create a firm-level variable for how much each of these groups is employed in a firm. I also construct a variable measuring firm’s offshoring, which is done following Feenstra & Hanson (1999). I estimate basic Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regressions to figure out how much exactly the offshoring of a firm affects the skill structure of a firm. I control for technological aspects and add firm and time specific effects. I perform this exercise also at the industry level, because it is more likely that the structure of industry is changing due to increasing offshoring. To assure causality I develop my own industry-level instrumental variable (following Autor et al. 2011), and run Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS) regressions. I find that there has been job polarization in Finland, where the middle skilled labour has lost approximately 7 percent points of its share between 2000 and 2008. Furthermore, I find that the losing occupations perform excessively routine tasks. In this study I find that offshoring does not explain job polarization very well at the firm level, when added firm and time specific effects. My instrumental variable approach states that offshoring does cause statistically significant demise in the share of the middle skilled at the industry level, but these results are subject to some doubt, since the instrumental variable might be weak. I conclude that offshoring might have an effect on job polarization, but this effect should not be overestimated. Like the previous literature, I come to the conclusion that routine-intensity of work might be better explanation for diminishing middle skilled labour than offshoring.
  • Silvo, Aino (2011)
    Ever since its initial introduction some fifty years ago, the rational expectations paradigm has dominated the way economic theory handles uncertainty. The main assertion made by John F. Muth (1961), seen by many as the father of the paradigm, is that expectations of rational economic agents should essentially be equal to the predictions of relevant economic theory, since rational agents should use information available to them in an optimal way. This assumption often has important consequences on the results and interpretations of the models where it is applied. Although the rational expectations assumption can be applied to virtually any economic theory, the focus in this thesis is on macroeconomic theories of consumption, especially the Rational Expectations–Permanent Income Hypothesis proposed by Robert E. Hall in 1978. The much-debated theory suggests that, assuming that agents have rational expectations on their future income, consumption decisions should follow a random walk, and the best forecast of future consumption level is the current consumption level. Then, changes in consumption are unforecastable. This thesis constructs an empirical test for the Rational Expectations–Permanent Income Hypothesis using Finnish Consumer Survey data as well as various Finnish macroeconomic data. The data sample covers the years 1995–2010. Consumer survey data may be interpreted to directly represent household expectations, which makes it an interesting tool for this particular test. The variable to be predicted is the growth of total household consumption expenditure. The main empirical result is that the Consumer Confidence Index (CCI), a balance figure computed from the most important consumer survey responses, does have statistically significant predictive power over the change in total consumption expenditure. The history of consumption expenditure growth itself, however, fails to predict its own future values. This indicates that the CCI contains some information that the history of consumption decisions does not, and that the consumption decisions are not optimal in the theoretical context. However, when conditioned on various macroeconomic variables, the CCI loses its predictive ability. This finding suggests that the index is merely a (partial) summary of macroeconomic information, and does not contain any significant private information on consumption intentions of households not directly deductible from the objective economic variables. In conclusion, the Rational Expectations–Permanent Income Hypothesis is strongly rejected by the empirical results in this thesis. This result is in accordance with most earlier studies conducted on the topic.
  • Kaukoranta, Ilkka (2009)
    This thesis studies empirically whether measurement errors in aggregate production statistics affect sentiment and future output. Initial announcements of aggregate production are subject to measurement error, because many of the data required to compile the statistics are produced with a lag. This measurement error can be gauged as the difference between the latest revised statistic and its initial announcement. Assuming aggregate production statistics help forecast future aggregate production, these measurement errors are expected to affect macroeconomic forecasts. Assuming agents’ macroeconomic forecasts affect their production choices, these measurement errors should affect future output through sentiment. This thesis is primarily empirical, so the theoretical basis, strategic complementarity, is discussed quite briefly. However, it is a model in which higher aggregate production increases each agent’s incentive to produce. In this circumstance a statistical announcement which suggests aggregate production is high would increase each agent’s incentive to produce, thus resulting in higher aggregate production. In this way the existence of strategic complementarity provides the theoretical basis for output fluctuations caused by measurement mistakes in aggregate production statistics. Previous empirical studies suggest that measurement errors in gross national product affect future aggregate production in the United States. Additionally it has been demonstrated that measurement errors in the Index of Leading Indicators affect forecasts by professional economists as well as future industrial production in the United States. This thesis aims to verify the applicability of these findings to other countries, as well as study the link between measurement errors in gross domestic product and sentiment. This thesis explores the relationship between measurement errors in gross domestic production and sentiment and future output. Professional forecasts and consumer sentiment in the United States and Finland, as well as producer sentiment in Finland, are used as the measures of sentiment. Using statistical techniques it is found that measurement errors in gross domestic product affect forecasts and producer sentiment. The effect on consumer sentiment is ambiguous. The relationship between measurement errors and future output is explored using data from Finland, United States, United Kingdom, New Zealand and Sweden. It is found that measurement errors have affected aggregate production or investment in Finland, United States, United Kingdom and Sweden. Specifically, it was found that overly optimistic statistics announcements are associated with higher output and vice versa.
  • Relander, Jarkko (2020)
    Pro-graduni käsittelee dopingin määrän vähentämistä urheilussa. Tutkin dopingin määrän vähentämistä urheilussa peliteoreettisin keinoin. Katson urheilua tutkimuksessani taloudelliselta kannalta. Tutkimukseni metodina käytän kirjallisuuskatsausta. Tutkimuksen motivaationa voidaan pitää nykyisen antidopingtoiminnan toimimattomuutta ja sitä, kuinka paljon rahaa urheilussa liikkuu. Täten on hyvä kitkeä urheilusta vilppi pois. Aiemmassa kirjallisuudessa voidaan erottaa selvästi kaksi eri tutkimus-suuntaa. Osa tutkimuksista keskittyy yksittäisten urheilijoiden kannustimeen käyttää dopingia. Osa tutkimuksista taas keskittyy siihen, kuinka antidopingorganisaatioiden toiminta ei ole uskottavaa. Kun tutkitaan dopingin määrän vähentämistä urheilussa dopingin käytön kannustimien vähentämisellä, voidaan saada seuraavia johtopäätöksiä. Yksi keino vähentää dopinginkäyttöä on lajien sääntömuutokset, jolloin urheilijat joutuvat tekniikkamuutoksiin ja täten dopingin vaikutus suoritukseen vähenee. Myös rangaistuksen koventaminen ja esimerkiksi sakkorangaistuksiin siirtyminen voisi toimia dopingin käytön kannustimen pienentämiseen. Kun dopingia ja harjoittelua katsotaan substituutteina, voidaan huomata antidopingtoiminnalla olevan myös haittapuolia, kuten harjoittelun kannustimen pieneneminen. Tämän takia myös sallittu suorituskyvyn parantaminen pitää ottaa huomioon rankaisumenetelmää mietittäessä. Jos taas dopingin käyttö ja sallittu suorituskyvyn parantaminen lasketaan komplementaarisiksi toisilleen todennäköisyysvaikutus vaikuttaa dopingin käyttöä kasvattavasti. Pohjapalkalla taas voidaan pienentää dopingin käytön kannustinta, sillä silloin voitosta saatava hyöty pienenee. Aikaisemmista tutkimuksista käy myös ilmi, kuinka sijoitusperusteinen rankaisujärestelmä toimisi dopingin ehkäisemisessä paremmin kuin tämän hetkinen järjestelmä, jossa urheilijoita rangaistaan tasavertaisesti sijoituksesta riippumatta. Antidopingorganisaatioiden uskottavuuden puutetta voidaan katsoa kahdelta kantilta; sekä kansainvälisellä antidopingorganisaatiolla että kansallisilla antidopingorganisaatioilla on omat uskottavuuden puutteensa. Kansallisen antidopingtoiminnan uskottavuuden puute liittyy siihen, kun organisaatiot ovat taloudellisesti sidoksista kansallisiin olympiakomiteoihin. Olympiakomiteat saavat helpommin rahoitusta, kun valtion urheilijat pärjäävät kilpailuissa ja tämä taas ajaa kansallista antidopingorganisaatiota höllentämään valvontaa. Tämä voidaan estää sillä, että kokonaisuudessaan antidopingtoimintaa hoitaa kansainvälinen organisaatio, sillä tällä ei ole kannustinta kohdella eri valtioiden urheilijoita eritasoisesti. Myös kansainvälisellä antidopingorganisaatiolla on oma uskottavuuden puutteensa, sillä se on taloudellisesti kytkettynä kansainväliseen olympiakomiteaan. Kiinnostus olympialaisia kohtaan romahtaisi, jos lajiensa huiput käryäisivät dopingista, eivätkä täten saisi osallistua olympiakilpailuihin. Tämän takia myös kansainvälisellä antidopingorganisaatiolla on kannustin lieventää dopingvalvontaa. Tämä voidaan estää tekemällä kansainvälisestä antidopingorganisaatiosta täysin riippumaton urheilukilpailuiden järjestäjistä. Toinen vaihtoehto on palkata antidopingtoiminnan johtajaksi henkilö, jonka inho dopingia kohtaan on pohjaton. Kolmas vaihtoehto kitkeä kansainvälisen antidopingtoiminnan luottamuspula on asettaa toiminnan johtajalle ”tulospalkkaus” tehdystä työstä.
  • Louhivuori, Valtter (2013)
    Innovations can be seen as an engine of long-term economic growth. Firms conduct research and development (R&D) activities to create new production technology, methods or products in order to rival their competitors. In addition to benefiting the inventor, new innovations have considerable positive externalities through knowledge spillovers. However, the socially optimal level of innovations may not be achieved, because firms can underinvest in R&D if they are not compensated for the positive externalities produced by their R&D activities. Public R&D programs aim to encourage innovation by compensating firms for the positive externalities that they produce. Finland’s recent public efforts on fostering innovation have been globally high by many indicators. Nevertheless, the effectiveness of these efforts has been relatively little scrutinised. This thesis studies the effectiveness of Finnish R&D program in fostering innovation outputs at the firm level. Firm-level patent statistics are used as a proxy for the innovativeness of a firm. A major contribution of this thesis is the comprehensive database that has been constructed and employed for the analysis. The database includes firm-level innovative characteristics for all the Finnish firms during a ten-year sample period, altogether covering more than two million observations for over 400 000 firms. Most of the studies on the effectiveness of the Finnish R&D program rely on the assumption that the researcher has full information on the relevant innovative characteristics that affect a firm’s program eligibility. This thesis addresses the program selectivity concern by employing an instrumental variable approach that exploits regional variation in public R&D funding stemming from the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF) aid regulations. The estimates suggest that when the program selection bias is neglected, program participation is associated with around 10 percentage point increase in patenting probability among active patentees, whereas for all firms, the increase in patenting probability is only around 0.1 percentage points. However, the instrumental variable estimates do not confirm any significant causal effect of R&D program on patenting. This thesis highlights the importance of accounting for the selection bias induced by the R&D program selection criteria. The public R&D agency is found to select firms strongly based on the same characteristics that are highly associated with innovation within firms. Therefore, it is important to ask if some of the supported firms might have had conducted their R&D projects even in the absence of the public support. Analysing the R&D program’s selection criteria plays a major role in scrutinising the effectiveness of public R&D subsidies and in the further development of public innovation policies.
  • Meriläinen, Jaakko (2013)
    The largest party holds more than half of the seats in every third Finnish local council and, thus, is likely to govern alone. It is namely the absolute majority that makes the decisions. In this study, I investigate, if single-party and coalition governed municipalities differ in economic outcomes. Theoretical considerations often rely on so-called common pool problem. Common pool models suggest that when there is a governing coalition, all parties want to target some spending to their core constituents, while costs are shared equally across all parties. This results in higher spending than in the case that one party would be governing. However, also contradictory arguments have been proposed. It has been suggested that, for instance, strategic use of debt or role of swing voters in elections could lead to higher spending under single-party government. In this study, I show evidence from Finnish municipalities that is consistent with the idea of common pool models. Following the recent development lines in empirical political economics, I exploit close elections as a source of exogenous variation using regression discontinuity design (RDD) adjusted to proportional system. It is assumed that close elections are as good as if they were random. Estimates suggest that single-party control decreases, on average, total expenditures and revenues by around 200 euros per capita. However, it seems that the effect gets smaller year by year. It could be that re-electoral incentives affect the behavior of parties that govern councils alone. I also analyze the effect in several areas of spending and revenues. The data set that I use in this study includes data from 445 municipalities for a varying number of years between 1980–2010, which makes 13,104 observations in total. These data cover results of 3,778 elections. This study develops a simple though new way of analyzing the research question. I use seat division rules to compute the running variable for the regression discontinuity design. Moreover, most previous studies on the topic compare outcomes in different countries. In this study, the outcomes are compared within the same system, i.e. all units share the same institutional background. Last, the topic has not been studied in the Finnish context before, even though single-party control is common phenomenon and municipalities have an important role in the Finnish system.
  • Vanhala, Vili (2019)
    Thesis aims to investigate the motivations of the 2018’s planned policy in Finland, that would have allowed small companies to lay off workers easier. Policy was motivated by small companies’ having more uncertainty about employment decisions. It was assumed that when companies that were small enough could dismiss workers more easily, they would hire more employees, which would increase overall employment. At first, thesis discusses about effort and employees in a more general level using the one difference of dismissal conditions that exists in the Finnish labor market. It is found that there are differences in the employment decisions: employers do not want to hire any worker, they know that some perform better than other and there are incentives to choose a suitable worker. From these results, discussion becomes about potential moral hazard that could cause small companies to be less willing to hire additional workers. It is theoretically motivated, that easing dismissal conditions could improve employment through increased effort that can follow from the easing of dismissal conditions. However, there is not found a moral hazard problem that could only exist in small companies. Small companies may have harder to find a suitable worker for the potentially open position. Moral hazard might not be the only thing that explains this. It can also be attributed to the different characteristics of small and large firms. In addition, even if the employment could increase when dismissal conditions are eased, effects would be relatively small in the theoretical framework.
  • Björklund, Jenna (2018)
    There has been a lot of discussion on the downsides of cash during the 2010’s, while the new payment innovations during this same decade have provoked speculation that cash use will decrease considerably, potentially even disappear, in the upcoming years. However, cash is still used quite extensively, and to my knowledge, no systematic review on drivers of cash use has been made to date. The purpose of this thesis is to fill this gap by providing literature reviews both on the theory explaining cash use and the empirical evidence on the drivers of cash use. Additionally, Finland will be used as an illustration to study the relevance of the existing theories and empirical evidence in an environment where practically no barriers on switching completely from cash use to card use exist. The theoretical models explaining the choice between cash and cards at points of sale are built on assumptions that the pecuniary and/or non-pecuniary costs of cash and cards use differ. Particularly, cards are assumed to be more expensive than cash in some regard, which explains the cash choice. Behaviour wise, cash use is associated with lower transaction value, lower income, higher amounts of cash in the wallet and using cash to monitor liquidity. In empirical literature, factors that affect the payment instrument choice at point of sale are traditionally divided into four categories: payment instrument attributes, transaction specific characteristics, demographic factors and habit. Three out of the four theoretical models presented in this thesis seem relevant in explaining cash use in the view of the empirical evidence, although alternative explanations for the observed behaviour can also be found. Also, several other drivers of cash use are identified. Additionally, as making payments is a very frequent action, it is suggested that habit might have a bigger role in the payment instrument choice than is traditionally assumed, with several of the drivers being potentially a manifestation of habitual behaviour. A considerable limitation of the existing literature is that it focuses solely on explaining and analysing cash use for transaction purposes at points of sale. However, cash is also used for person-to-person transactions and as a store of value, and the reasons for cash use probably differ a lot in these other two use cases. Due to well-developed infrastructure, and cheap and fast card payments, many of the drivers of cash use identified by theoretical models and empirical evidence cannot explain cash use in Finland. In 2016 Finnish people used cash to pay small transactions, to control spending, because they perceived it to be easy to use, when they obtained it from another person or out of habit. Due to the quickly growing popularity of contactless card payments and the mobile phone applications for making easy person-to-person transactions, it is likely, that in future cash will decrease remarkably and it is mainly driven by the need to control spending, difficulty in using electronic payment instruments and habit.
  • David, Leticia Screta (2014)
    This thesis studies the consumers’ willingness to pay for renewable electricity. Green electricity consumption induced by improved information on electricity sources appears as an additional alternative to renewable energy support policies in practice today. It is believed that a shift of the demand towards green sources can stimulate renewable generation and have a positive impact on the environment. However, this voluntary initiative will only work if it is perceived worth paying a premium for green electricity. This work aims to examine the drivers of consumers’ behaviour towards green electricity and to develop economic models that embrace these findings. The analysis also elucidates how the demand for renewable electricity is affected by market prices and by consumers’ income and how information and advertising campaigns can stimulate the behaviour towards green electricity so that the voluntary demand system can fully achieve its goals.
  • Fornaro, Paolo (2011)
    In recent years, thanks to developments in information technology, large-dimensional datasets have been increasingly available. Researchers now have access to thousands of economic series and the information contained in them can be used to create accurate forecasts and to test economic theories. To exploit this large amount of information, researchers and policymakers need an appropriate econometric model.Usual time series models, vector autoregression for example, cannot incorporate more than a few variables. There are two ways to solve this problem: use variable selection procedures or gather the information contained in the series to create an index model. This thesis focuses on one of the most widespread index model, the dynamic factor model (the theory behind this model, based on previous literature, is the core of the first part of this study), and its use in forecasting Finnish macroeconomic indicators (which is the focus of the second part of the thesis). In particular, I forecast economic activity indicators (e.g. GDP) and price indicators (e.g. consumer price index), from 3 large Finnish datasets. The first dataset contains a large series of aggregated data obtained from the Statistics Finland database. The second dataset is composed by economic indicators from Bank of Finland. The last dataset is formed by disaggregated data from Statistic Finland, which I call micro dataset. The forecasts are computed following a two steps procedure: in the first step I estimate a set of common factors from the original dataset. The second step consists in formulating forecasting equations including the factors extracted previously. The predictions are evaluated using relative mean squared forecast error, where the benchmark model is a univariate autoregressive model. The results are dataset-dependent. The forecasts based on factor models are very accurate for the first dataset (the Statistics Finland one), while they are considerably worse for the Bank of Finland dataset. The forecasts derived from the micro dataset are still good, but less accurate than the ones obtained in the first case. This work leads to multiple research developments. The results here obtained can be replicated for longer datasets. The non-aggregated data can be represented in an even more disaggregated form (firm level). Finally, the use of the micro data, one of the major contributions of this thesis, can be useful in the imputation of missing values and the creation of flash estimates of macroeconomic indicator (nowcasting).
  • Antipina, Dina (2013)
    The subject of our research is the behavior of the economy in response to monetary and technology shocks. To understand these issues we use a Dynamic Money-in-the-Utility-Function framework. We implement a non-separable property of the utility function that implies non-neutrality of real money balances. We construct a toy theoretic model with two representative agents who maximize their functions subject to constraints. We analytically solve the model using a method of log-linearization around the steady state and obtain the system of linear equations. We analyze the response of economic equilibrium with respect to implemented shocks using a method of undetermined coefficients and solve a system of linear difference expectation equations. In addition to analytical solution we also present Impulse Response Functions of the model. We compute the impacts of monetary and technology shocks on the model and find that in case of a positive monetary shock expected inflation effect dominates the liquidity effect, while in case of a positive productivity shock income effect dominates substitution effect. The findings regarding the impact of a technology shock contradict the theory of real business cycles that predicts the domination of substitution effect over the income effect
  • Mielikäinen, Lasse (2016)
    Dynamic scoring is an approach, which strives to take into account the effects that public policy changes and changes in the law have on the macroeconomic variables. Scoring is an estimate of the effects the policy change is expected to bring. Compared to the traditional approach, dynamic scoring offers more information of the effects, but does this with increased uncertainty. In their paper “Dynamic scoring: A back-of-the-envelope guide” (2006) N. Gregory Mankiw and Matthew Weinzierl use neoclassical growth model, or Ramsey growth model, to examine how large a part of capital and labor income tax cuts pay for themselves by inducing higher economic growth, i.e. the size of the dynamic feedback effect. Their focus is on the changes of tax revenue. They use first a basic model with Cobb-Douglas production and inelastic labor supply, then relax those assumptions for a more general Ramsey model and then in turn include parameters allowing for finite horizon households, imperfect competition, and externalities to capital investment. Depending on the model used, the dynamic feedback effect varies from model to model, for a capital tax cut from 50 to 74 percent and for a labor income tax cut from zero (with inelastic labor supply) to 21 percent. This thesis extends the Mankiw–Weinzierl model by including a tax on consumption to examine how this affects the dynamic feedback effect. In all the models, there is an increase in the dynamic feedback effect: depending on the model used, it varies for a capital tax cut from 60 to 87 percent and for a labor income tax cut from zero (with inelastic labor supply) to 25 percent. The values of some of the key parameters, namely the constant-consumption elasticity of labor supply and the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor, and the tax rates are revised as well. This further increases the dynamic feedback effect all along the line, in some cases even suggesting a capital tax cut to more than compensate the static revenue loss. Including a tax on consumption into the models increases the dynamic feedback effect, working into the same direction as rising the initial rates of capital and labor income taxes. Using alternative tax rates and values of the key parameters also has a significant impact on the size of the dynamic feedback effect.